Why Is It So Expensive to Read Academic Research?
Content piracy may be illegal, but price gouging is at least as despicable.
The aphorism “information wants to be free,”
coined by entrepreneur Stewart Brand in 1984 at the inaugural Hackers
Conference, has come to serve as a shorthand justification for an ideology that
would remove all unjust barriers to information access. And information has
rarely been more accessible than it is on the controversial website Sci-Hub, which offers completely free access to
pretty much any academic journal article ever published. The site does this
through what is commonly termed “content piracy” and has been in the news
lately because academic publishers are trying very hard to shut the
website down.
They aren’t having much success: It’s hosted
overseas, and its proprietor, the Kazakh researcher Alexandra
Elbakyan, does not seem particularly worried about the niceties of
U.S. copyright law, much to her opponents’ dismay. (Academic publisher Elsevier
is attempting to sue Elbakyan in federal court and won a preliminary injunction
last year that temporarily shuttered Sci-Hub; the site soon returned under a
different domain name.) “It’s as if somehow stealing content is justifiable if
it’s seen as expensive, and I find that surprising,” Alicia Wise, director of
universal access at Elsevier, recently told the New York Times in an article
about Elbakyan’s unrepentant redistributionism. “It’s not as if you’d walk into
a grocery store and feel vindicated about stealing an organic chocolate bar as
long as you left the Kit Kat bar on the shelf.”
The chocolate bar analogy is a bad one—haute
bourgeois candy bars and academic research papers have very little in common
except that you will probably get sick if you eat too many of either—but let’s
stick with it for a minute. Why is that organic chocolate bar so expensive in
the first place? Sure, the consumer is paying a premium for the word “organic,”
but organic chocolate is also more expensive to produce. The manufacturer,
knowing that there is elastic demand for fancy chocolate, has presumably set
the purchase price at a level where the company can cover its costs and turn a
profit—all while not alienating the consumer. If a candymaker decided to charge
$5,000 for an organic chocolate bar, consumers wouldn’t respond by stealing the
pricey bar; they’d simply buy another brand of chocolate, and the initial
company would either adjust its price or go bankrupt.
When a publisher of academic journals decides
to charge $5,000 for a yearly subscription, though, subscribers might grumble
about the price but they will often still pay it. This isn’t just a
hypothetical situation: Plenty of specialized scientific journals charge $5,000
and more for yearly subscriptions. So why are academic journals so expensive?
The economics of academic publishing are
fundamentally different from those of general book publishing, or journalism,
or the chocolate industry. The latter enterprises specialize in products that
members of the general public might conceivably want to purchase but don’t
need. There are quite a few members of the general public, and in order to
attract as many of them as possible, commercial publishers set relatively low
prices for their products, hoping to realize profit through sales volume. Many
online news sources, including Slate,
choose to attract an audience by offering their content for free and earn money
primarily from advertising rather than sales revenue.
Many of these new, small journals became
affiliated with existing publishing groups like Elsevier. In exchange for
ownership of the copyrights of the articles they print, these publishers agree
to coordinate the peer-review process and format, distribute, and archive these
journals. These big publishers could scale the same template they used for the
publication of one
journal to many
journals. Reasoning that the research results contained in these small,
esoteric journals would be very valuable to certain people—even if there are
only 100 professors in the world who actually need to read Fluid Dynamics Geometric Titration
Quarterly (note: not a real journal), those 100 professors will be
upset if their libraries don’t have it—and observing that academic libraries
seemed committed to buying every new journal that came out, the publishers
started exploiting this inelastic demand and raising subscription prices,
regularly and predictably. This situation became known as the “serials pricing
crisis.”
The serials pricing crisis has been busting
academic libraries’ budgets—and creating ever-widening information gaps between
rich and poor countries—since the 1970s, when subscription prices to academic
journals first started rising faster than the rate of inflation. In his book Open Access, Peter Suber
observed that “In 2008, Harvard subscribed to 98,900 serials and Yale to
73,900. The best-funded research library in India, at the Indian Institute of
Science, subscribed to 10,600. Several sub-Saharan African university libraries
subscribed to zero, offering their patrons access to no conventional journals
except those donated by publishers.” The rich get richer, the poor make do with
dusty old copies of National
Geographic.
It’s unfortunate, but not particularly
surprising, that some sub-Saharan universities cannot afford to keep up with
the latest in academic research. But it turns out that even Harvard is
struggling to afford all of its journal subscriptions; in 2008, Suber noted in Open Access, “cumulative
price increases had forced the Harvard library to undertake ‘serious
cancellation efforts’ for budgetary reasons.” Harvard’s dilemma has not
improved much since then: Suber recently told
the New York Times that the university
continues to struggle to afford its journal subscriptions even though “it has
the largest budget of any academic library in the world.”
The open access movement—Sci-Hub belongs to
its most radical wing—began in the 1990s in direct response to the serials
pricing crisis. Its founders realized that the Internet could minimize
production and distribution costs, and offer a potential solution to academic
stratification and the serials pricing crisis. Today, open-access advocates
argue in favor of making academic research papers freely accessible to other
researchers and scholars, and emphasize the immense public benefit of making
scholarly research accessible to the world at large. With Sci-Hub, Elbakyan is
trying to speed this outcome. “Before Sci-Hub, all research on a massive scale
was closed behind paywalls, and now anyone can access it! It will be impossible
to shut down the website completely, so that change is forever,” she wrote
earlier this year. “[T]he effect of long-term operation of Sci-Hub
will be that publishers change their publishing models to support Open Access,
because closed access will make no sense anymore.”
No comments:
Post a Comment